Decentralizing the Provision of Health Services : An Incomplete Contracts Approach
The author studies the allocation-between a central government and a local authority--of responsibility for planning, financing, and operations for the delivery of health services, in the context of an incomplete contracts model. In this model,...
Main Author: | |
---|---|
Format: | Policy Research Working Paper |
Language: | English en_US |
Published: |
World Bank Group, Washington, DC
2014
|
Subjects: | |
Online Access: | http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2000/07/443601/decentralizing-provision-health-services-incomplete-contracts-approach http://hdl.handle.net/10986/19827 |
Summary: | The author studies the
allocation-between a central government and a local
authority--of responsibility for planning, financing, and
operations for the delivery of health services, in the
context of an incomplete contracts model. In this model,
inputs are required of both the central government and local
authorities but they are unable to write down, and commit
to, a complete and binding contract describing the actions
both should take. The model is meant to capture the tradeoff
between central and local authority in decisions about both
financing and the provision of services. Each party provides
a specific input--for example, the central government
establishes a drug procurement system while the local
authority designs and implements an incentive scheme to get
doctors to carry out their responsibilities appropriately.
The responsibility for delivery of services is identified
with the ownership of essential infrastructure, such as the
clinic or hospital. The author finds that to maximize the
joint surplus of the two public bodies: Ownership of the
facility should be given to the party that most values the
well-being of local residents. (This way, if ex post
bargaining breaks down, each still enjoys some benefits from
the other's actions.) Financing authority and
responsibility for delivering services should be negatively
correlated. Generally it is optimal to allocate tax
authority to the party that values the residents'
well-being less--in other words, separate spending
responsibility (ownership) from financing authority. A
heavier financing burden (access to a small and inefficient
tax base) has the same incentive effect as asset ownership:
It increases the return to effort. If transferring ownership
of the physical asset is costly (because the party that
builds the asset has an inherent advantage in operating
it-that is, there is some human capital embodiment), it may
be optimal for the party with the higher construction costs
to have planning authority. Somewhat paradoxically, the
greater the costs of transferring assets from one party to
the other, the more likely that ownership of the facilities
and their provision should be separated. |
---|